growth in the size and sales of urban breweries. The 1576 restriction was re newed in 1600 but at least by then brewing in Flushing was no longer in the rural category and so not subject to the legislation14. By that time Flushing had a growing industry. Rural producers did not have to pay taxes and rural property was less expensive as well. Already in 1497 Middelburg imposed clear, emphatic and simple regulation of brewing beyond the limits of her ju risdiction. No resident of the town who earned his daily bread in Middelburg was allowed to buy, drink, or bring in beer from outside the town. A 1504 by law made a similar restriction but only for one year. In the other direction in 1570 Middelburg prohibited the sale of beer produced in the town to rural buyers, but that was only when supplies in town were inadequate for Middel burg drinkers. A number of towns in the Low Countries set a limitation on the size of each brew in the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries but in Zeeland there were only two cases, 1540 at Veere where the number of barrels that could be made at any one time was set at a maximum of 40 and 1598 at Flushing but there it was not a maximum but rather a minimum set at 20 bar- rels45. In the first instance the desire was to prevent too great a concentration of the industry in the hands of only big breweries. In the latter the goal was the same as at Middelburg in 1453, to keep small part time producers out of the industry, to promote quality and the development of the industry. By 1598 Flushing was succeeding in that consistent goal. The towns of Zeeland never gave up manipulating taxes and regulations for the protection of their own industries and protection of their tax incomes. If the circumstances of the brewing industry turned truly bad, as they did in Veere in 1567, then towns could resort to temporary embargoes on all im ported beer. Such restrictions were never expected to last and so did not draw the ire of other towns. There could be, without much fear of political reprisal, long term heavy taxes on English and German beers. Those imports were common targets of very high rates of excise. Taxes for publicans were often prorated, based on the price of the beer sold. In Zeeland under ordinances of 1637 the same practice was followed as in Holland, with the highest rates of tax reserved for joopenbier, a very thick and hearty type from Gdansk used largely for medicinal purposes. There were even distinctions in the rates for different types of English beer. Holland beers, though foreign imports as well, were favoured in taxing over beers from Ltibeck and England. In 1572 Flushing dropped the excise on locally brewed beer while raising that on beer from Holland and Utrecht and raising it even more on foreign beers4". The changes were drastic and contrary to existing agreements and regulations. They seem to have brought little notice, perhaps in part because of the Revolt 44. ZA. Arch. Sl.v.Z.: inv.nr. 3227, 1576. inv.nr. 3228. 1600; H. Soly. "De economische betekenis van de Zuidnederlandse brouwinduslrie in de 16c eeuw. Problematiek", in Handelingen van hel Col loquium over de economische geschiedenis van België. Behandelingen van de bronnen en prob- lemaiiek (Brussels 1972) 113-114; Unger, Bronnen, vol. 3. nr. 205. 45. GAVe, inv.nr. 311: fols. 96v-97v; Unger, Bronnen, vol.2, nrs. 114 and 120, vol.3, nr. 860. 46. GAVe, inv.nr. 311: fols. 5r-6r, I57r; ZA. Arch. St.v.Z.: inv.nr. 3227, [15741; C. Cau el al., Groot Placaeilboek, vol.l. 2048-2059; Winkelman, Vlissingen183-184. 18

Tijdschriftenbank Zeeland

Archief | 1999 | | pagina 28